Skip to main content
Log in

A general model of the innovation - subjective well-being nexus

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A model of the innovation – subjective well-being (SWB) nexus is needed to advance our understanding of the welfare implications of innovation. Building on an earlier contribution by Swann (G. M. Peter Swann, 2009, The Economics of Innovation, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK), I first assemble the major building blocks of such a model and then discuss some of the many potential linkages between them. A central feature is the inclusion of multiple SWB impacts of processes as well as of outcomes. Some general issues that would have to be addressed in any empirical application are also discussed. SWB impacts are to be used as an additional indicator in the assessment of innovation, not as something to be maximised. By taking SWB into account, new insights might emerge that could result in either strengthening or modifying existing innovation policies, or in novel policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. They include John Stuart Mill, Karl Marx, Ernst Friedrich Schumacher (see Swann 2009), as well as Richard Layard (2005), Diane Coyle (2011), among others.

  2. See Schubert (2012a, p. 586, footnote 2) for references to other evolutionary economists who have written on normative issues. Also see Dolfsma (2008, chapter 8), who aims to develop a dynamic Schumpeterian welfare perspective which focuses on long-term effects. However, he still equates social welfare with total output.

  3. The term happiness research is somewhat unfortunate because of its hedonistic connotations. In the economics literature it is synonymous with SWB research. I use it in that broad sense.

  4. Elsewhere I have highlighted the lack of links between the literature on policies for KBEs and that on policy implications of happiness research (see Engelbrecht 2007, 2012).

  5. Some of their examples of policy uses of SWB measures are relevant in the context of the innovation-SWB nexus, e.g. the discussion of unemployment and well-being in the workplace (Diener et al. 2009, chapter 10). The closest they come to commenting on innovation is a brief mention of the lack of knowledge of SWB impacts of technological change (ibid., p. 117).

  6. For example challenge 1 ‘from visible innovation to ‘dark innovation”, challenge 6 ‘from innovation for economic productivity to innovation for sustainability (‘green innovation’)’, challenge 7 ‘from risky innovation to socially responsible innovation’ and challenge 8 ‘from innovation for wealth creation to innovation for well-being (or from ‘more is better‘ to ‘enough is enough’)’.

  7. Ruskinian wealth is named after John Ruskin, the British philosopher and art historian.

  8. For example, the optimal level of SWB might be less than the highest level possible, it might vary between life domains and individuals, and there might be acceptable trade-offs between SWB and other objectives (Oishi et al. 2007). There is a large literature on the issue of whether policies should, or should not, maximise happiness. Hirata (2011) provides a good overview of the debate.

  9. Binder (2013, p. 568) argues that this view can be termed the constitutional or institutional approach to happiness politics, whereas SWB maximisation can be termed the welfare economic approach. Although I broadly agree with the constitutional view, Binder’s view of policy seems to be more hands-off then mine, aiming only at creating institutional frameworks that allow individuals to pursue SWB. I would argue that the model of the innovation-SWB nexus might also be used to identify discretionary policy interventions that aim at supporting SWB without trying to maximise it.

  10. 10 It also hints at the issue of how to combine different SWB impacts, i.e. in this case overall SWB versus SWB in the workplace, an issue commented on further in Section 3.2.

  11. Schumpeter firmly associated entrepreneurship with innovation. For a brief introduction to theories of creativity and entrepreneurship see, e.g., Swann (2009, chapters 9, 10).

  12. For a brief introduction to the issues, see Swann (2009, chapter 18).

  13. TW is conceptualised as the present value of (sustainable) consumption over a generation. Major TW subcategories are natural, produced and intangible capital. Measurement of natural capital is improving quickly, but it is still incomplete, excluding important resources like water and fisheries. Numerous assumptions have to be made when calculating natural and produced capital. They can and have been critisized (see, e.g., Perman et al. 2011). By far the largest component of TW is intangible capital. Due to lack of adequate data for many countries it is simply measured as a residual in World Bank (2011). The alternative approach of estimating all capital stocks directly and adding them up to obtain TW, plus correcting for a number of other issues associated with ‘wealth accounting’, has been advocated by Dasgupta (2010) and Arrow et al. (2010).

  14. Such as the Happy Planet Index (New Economics Foundation 2009) that combines happy life years (life satisfaction × life expectancy) and an adjusted ecological footprint; or Ng’s (2008) environmentally responsible happy nation index.

  15. A detailed discussion of different SWB measures is beyond the scope of this paper. For further discussion see, e.g., Diener et al. (2009) and Helliwell et al. (2012).

  16. For example, happiness seems to satiate with high income, whereas LSF does not. Earlier, Inglehart et al. (2008) reported that a society’s level of LSF is more closely related to economic conditions than is happiness.

  17. The multitude of potential SWB measures, even when the same general definition of SWB is used, indicates the need for some standardization, which will hopefully take the form of integrated national systems of SWB accounts.

  18. Personal communication, 30 April 2013.

  19. This resonates with Schumpeter’s view of the complexity of any normative analysis of creative destruction that led him to abandon any attempt at it (Schumpeter 1947, p. 155, footnote 12, reported in Schubert 2013, p. 228).

  20. For an introduction to the Easterlin Paradox controversy see Clark et al. (2008) and Easterlin et al. (2010). If it is accepted that economic growth in advanced KBEs is mostly due to productivity growth (which itself is mostly due to innovation), the literature on the Easterlin Paradox is highly relevant to the analysis of the innovation-SWB nexus.

  21. One example is Dolan and Metcalfe (2012). Using a representative survey of the British population and new primary data, they find a strong link between innovation (proxied alternatively by being original and having imagination) and SWB (in the workplace and in life generally). They point out that more research is needed to determine causation. Their explanatory variables mostly capture personal attributes, some of which can be mapped into the model of the innovation-SWB nexus, but many potentially important factors are not included.

  22. For an introduction to the literature on consumer resistance to innovation adoption see Kleijnen et al. (2009).

  23. Frey et al. (2004, p. 385/6) argue, e.g., that “hierarchy constitutes a procedural disutility because it interferes with innate needs of self-determination”.

  24. For example, Kavetsos and Koutroumpis (2011) find positive correlations for some products and argue this might have implications for public policy, e.g. for recognising internet access as a fundamental human right.

  25. See, e.g., Uhlaner and Thurik (2007) for findings derived from macro-level cross-country data, and Block and Koellinger (2009) and Carree and Verheul (2012) for findings obtained using micro-level data.

  26. Binder (2013) wants to impose more structure on the SWB analysis of innovations by restricting analysis to “life domains which impact on subjective well-being regardless of context and culture” (ibid., p. 572). He calls this his ‘life domain evaluation principle’. However, he is not very specific about what domains to include. There are potentially some similarities to several of the elements included in my general model, but his formulation seems overly restrictive.

  27. See Dopfer et al. (2004) on the importance of the meso in evolutionary economics. They argue meso change is central for understanding evolutionary dynamics.

  28. I do not assume preferences are unchanging over time. However, I do not explicitly comment on the issue of endogenous preferences in this paper, an issue which is central to Schubert’s (2012a, b, 2013) work. The relationship between preference learning and SWB is a complex one that should be explored further.

  29. See, e.g., Hirata (2011, pp. 59–63).

  30. Binder (2013) proposes a second normative evaluation rule, i.e. the ‘welfare dynamics principle’, that is aimed at imposing structure on the SWB analyses of innovation over the medium and long run. It focuses exclusively on hedonic adaptation dynamics. While undoubtedly ambitious and challenging, it leaves out other dynamic relationships of the innovation-SWB nexus.

  31. While Schubert argues there needs to be novelty (and therefore uncertainty) so that people can learn new preferences, he does not highlight the potential impacts of uncertainty on SWB. Not only is it unclear how his approach can be implemented empirically, I would also argue that preference learning is not the same as welfare or well-being. It has its own SWB impacts, which are part of the dynamic relationships of the innovation-SWB nexus.

  32. Lundvall (2011), e.g., acknowledges links between the quality of work, learning opportunities and innovation, and job satisfaction.

  33. This would also apply to other types of innovation systems, e.g. regional, sectoral, or technological.

  34. On wisdom-based knowledge policies see, e.g., Rooney and McKenna (2005) and Rooney et al. (2010). The need to move from an information and KBE to a wisdom economy has also been pointed out by others, e.g. by Daly (1996), one of the founders of ecological economics.

References

  • Akçomak S, ter Weel B (2009) Social capital, innovation and growth: evidence from Europe. Eur Econ Rev 53(5):544–567

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K, Dasgupta P, Goulder L, Mumford K, Oleson K (2010) Sustainability and the measurement of wealth. Working Paper 16599, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

  • Beaumont J (2011) Measuring national well-being–discussion paper on domains and measures. Office for National Statistics, UK

  • Benkler Y (2006) The wealth of networks: how social production transforms markets and freedom. Yale University Press, New Haven and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Binder M (2013) Innovativeness and subjective well-being. Soc Indic Res 111:561–578

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Block J, Koellinger P (2009) I can’t get no satisfaction–necessity entrepreneurship and procedural utility. Kyklos 62(2):191–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boldrin M, Levine D (2008) Perfectly competitive innovation. J Monetary Econ 55:435–453

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bryson A, Dale-Olsen H, Barth E (2013) The effects of organizational change on worker well-being and the moderating role of trade unions. Ind Labor Relat Rev 66:989–1011

    Google Scholar 

  • Carree M, Verheul I (2012) What makes entrepreneurs happy? Determinants of satisfaction amongst founders. J Happiness Stud 13(2):371–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark A, Frijters P, Shields M (2008) Relative income, happiness, and utility: an explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and other puzzles. J Econ Lit 46(1):95–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen D (2003) Our modern times: the new nature of capitalism in the information age. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Commission of the European Communities (2009) GDP and beyond: measuring progress in a changing world. Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, COM (2009), 433 final, Brussels

  • Coyle D (2011) The economics of enough: how to run the economy as if the future matters. Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Csikszentmihalyi M (1990) Flow: the psychology of optimal experience. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Daly H (1996) Beyond growth: the economics of sustainable development. Beacon Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P (2010) The place of nature in economic development. In: Rodrik D, Rosenzweig M (eds) Handbook of development economics, vol 5. North-Holland/Elsevier BV, Amsterdam, pp 4977–5046

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A, Stone AA (2013) Two happiness puzzles. Am Econ Rev 103(3):591–597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diener E, Seligman M (2004) Beyond money: toward an economy of well-being. Psychol Sci Public Interest 5(1):1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diener E, Lucas R, Schimmack U, Helliwell J (2009) Well-being for public policy. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dolan P, Metcalfe R (2012) The relationship between innovation and subjective well-being. Res Pol 41:1489–1498

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolan P, White M (2007) How can measures of subjective well-being be used to inform public policy?Perspect Psychol Sci 2(1):71–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolfsma W (2008) Knowledge economies: organization, location and innovation. Routledge, London and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K, Foster J, Potts J (2004) Micro-meso-macro. J Evol Econ 14:263–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drucker P (1999) Knowledge-worker productivity: the biggest challenge. Calif Manage Rev 41(2):79– 94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin R, Angelescu McVey L, Switek M, Sawangfa O, Smith Zweig J (2010) The happiness-income paradox revisited. PNAS 107(52):22463–22468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The Economist (2011) The geology of the planet: welcome to the Anthropocene. May 26th, p 14

  • Edquist C (2005) Systems of innovation: perspectives and challenges. In: Fagerberg J, Mowery DC, Nelson RR (eds) The Oxford handbook of innovation. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York, pp 181–208

    Google Scholar 

  • Engelbrecht HJ (2007) The (un)happiness of knowledge and the knowledge of (un)happiness: Happiness research and policies for knowledge-based economies. Prometheus 25(3):243–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engelbrecht HJ (2012) Knowledge-based economies and subjective well-being. In: David Rooney D, Hearn G, Kastelle T (eds) Handbook on the knowledge economy, volume 2. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham and Northampton, pp 54–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Eppler M, Mengis J (2004) The concept of information overload: a review of literature from organization science, accounting, marketing, MIS, and related disciplines. Inf Soc 20(5):325–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foray D (2006) Optimizing the use of knowledge. In: Kahin B, Foray D (eds) Advancing knowledge and the knowledge economy. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 9–15

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey B, Benz M, Stutzer A (2004) Introducing procedural utility: not only what, but also how matters. J Institut Theor Econ 160:377–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham C (2011) The pursuit of happiness: an economy of well-being. The Brookings Institution, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell J, Huang H (2010) How’s the job? Well-being and social capital in the workplace. Ind Labor Relat Rev 63(2):205–227

    Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell J, Putnam R (2004) The social context of well-being. Phil Trans R Soc London B 359:1435–1446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell J, Wang S (2009) Trust and well-being. Paper presented at The 3rd OECD World Forum on Statistics, Knowledge and Policy: Charting Progress, Building Visions, Improving Life, Busan Korea, 27–30 October 2009. http://www.oecd. org/dataoecd/55/17/43964059.pdf. Accessed 5 May 2012

  • Helliwell J, Layard R, Sachs J (eds) (2012) World happiness report. The Earth Institute, Columbia University, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirata J (2011) Happiness, ethics and economics. Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, London and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Høyrup S, Bonnafous-Boucher M, Hasse C, Lotz M, Møller K (eds) (2012) Employee-driven innovation: a new approach. Palgrave MacMillan, New York and Houndmills, Basingstoke

  • Inglehart R, Welzel C (2005) Modernization, cultural change, and democracy: the human development sequence. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart R, Basanez M, Diez-Medrano J, Halman L, Luijkx R (2004) Human beliefs and values: a cross-cultural sourcebook based on the 1999–2002 values surveys. Siglo XXI Editores, Mexico

  • Inglehart R, Foa R, Peterson C, Welzel C (2008) Development, freedom, and rising happiness: a global perspective. Perspect Psychol Sci 3(4):264–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jolly D, Saltmarsh M (2009) Suicides in France put focus on workplace. The New York Times, September 29th. (accessed on-line January 9th, 2012)

  • Kahneman D, Deaton A (2010) High income improves evaluation of life but not emotional well-being. PNAS 107(38):16489–16493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kavetsos G, Koutroumpis P (2011) Technological affluence and subjective well-being. J Econ Psychol 32:742–753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleijnen M, Lee N, Wetzels M (2009) An exploration of consumer resistance to innovation and its antecedents. J Econ Psychol 30(3):344–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger A, Kahneman D, Schkade D, Schwarz N, Stone A (2009) National time accounting: the currency of life. In: Krueger A (ed) Measuring the subjective well-being of nations: national accounts of time use and well-being. University of Chicago Press, Chicago and London, pp 9–86

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R (2005) Happiness: lessons from a new science. Penguin Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall BÅ (1992) Introduciton. In: Lundvall BÅ (ed) National systems of innovation: towards a theory of innovation and interactive learning. Pinter Publishers, London, pp 1–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall BÅ (2011) Notes on innovation systems and economic development. Innov Dev 1(1):25–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manyika J, Chui M, Bughin J, Dobbs R, Bisson P, Marrs A (2013) Disruptive technologies: advances that will transform life, business, and the global economy. McKinsey Global Institute

  • Martin BR (2012) Innovation studies: Challenging the boundaries. In: Lundvall Symposium on the Future of Innovation Studies, 16–17 February 2012, Aalborg University. The submitted version, available at http://sro.sussex.ac.uk/38701/. Accessed 4 April 2013

  • New Economics Foundation (2009) The happy planet index 2.0. London. www.happyplanetindex.org., Accessed 5 May 2012

  • New Economics Foundation (2011) National accounts of well-being. http://www. nationalaccountsofwellbeing.org/learn/measuring/. Accessed 5 May 2012

  • Ng YK (2008) Environmentally responsible happy nation index: towards an internationally acceptable national success indicator. Soc Indic Res 85(3):425–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng W, Diener E, Aurora R, Harter J (2009) Affluence, feelings of stress, and well-being. Soc Indic Res 94(2):257–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2005) The measurement of scientific and technological activities - Oslo manual: guidelines for collecting and interpreting innovation data, 3rd edn. Commission Eurostat, Paris

  • OECD (2011) How’s life? Measuring well-being. Paris

  • OECD (2012) Sick on the job? Myths and realities about mental health at work. Paris

  • Oishi S, Diener E, Lucas R (2007) The optimum level of well-being: can people be too happy?Perspect Psychol Sci 2(4):346–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perman R, Ma Y, Common M, Maddison D, McGilvray J (2011) Natural resource and environmental economics, 4th edn. Pearson Education Ltd, Harlow

    Google Scholar 

  • Phelps E (2007) Macroeconomics for a modern economy. Am Econ Rev 97(3):543–561

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps E (2009) Refounding capitalism. Capital Soc 4(3):11, Article 2

    Google Scholar 

  • Rooney D, McKenna B (2005) Should the knowledge-based economy be a savant or a sage? Wisdom and socially intelligent innovation. Prometheus 23(3):307–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rooney D, McKenna B, Liesch P (2010) Wisdom and management in the knowledge economy. Routledge, New York and Abingdon

    Google Scholar 

  • Rooney D, Hearn G, Kastelle T (2012) Knowledge is people doing things, knowledge economies are people doing things with better outcomes for more people. In: Rooney D, Hearn G, Kastelle T (eds) Handbook on the knowledge economy, volume two. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham and Northampton, pp 1–14

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schubert C (2012a) Is novelty always a good thing? Towards an evolutionary welfare economics. J Evol Econ 22(3):585–619

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schubert C (2012b) Pursuing happiness. Kyklos 65(2):245–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schubert C (2013) How to evaluate creative destruction: reconstructing Schumpeter’s approach. Cambr J Econ 37:227–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1947) The creative response in economic history. J Econ Hist 7(2):149–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz B (2004) The paradox of choice: why more is less. HarperCollins Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Stehnken T, Muller E, Zenker A (2011) Happiness and innovation: avenues for further research, evoREG Research Note #18, November, 6 pages. http://www.evoreg.eu/docs/files/shno/Note_evoREG_18.pdf. Accessed 5 May2012

  • Stiglitz J, Sen A, Fitoussi J-P (2009) Report by the commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress. www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr. Accessed 5 May 2012

  • Stoneman P (2010) Soft innovation: economics, product aesthetics, and the creative industries. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Swann GMP (2009) The economics of innovation: an introduction. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham and Northampton, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Uhlaner L, Thurik R (2007) Postmaterialism influencing total entrepreneurial activity across nations. J Evol Econ 17(2):161–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel E (1988) The sources of innovation. Oxford University Press, New York and Oxford. http://web.mit.edu/evhippel/www/sources.htm. Accessed 5 May 2012

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel E (2005) Democratizing innovation. MIT Press, Cambridge. http://web.mit.edu/evhippel/www/democ1.htm. Accessed 5 May 2012

    Google Scholar 

  • Warr P (2007) Work, happiness, and unhappiness. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2011) The changing wealth of nations: measuring sustainable development in the new millennium. Washington, D.C.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hans-Jürgen Engelbrecht.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Engelbrecht, HJ. A general model of the innovation - subjective well-being nexus. J Evol Econ 24, 377–397 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-014-0343-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-014-0343-y

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation