Skip to main content

Frame of reference and conceptual approach for the analysis of individual retirement-specific financial planning behavior

  • Chapter
Book cover Individual Financial Planning for Retirement

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

Abstract

The frame of reference for this study provides the background for the analyses and statements about individual retirement-specific FPB. It consists of three elements: First, the inter-temporal financial optimization problem that individuals face with regard to financial planning for retirement is introduced. Second, financial planning as the major tool for financial provision in retirement and the study-specific definition of FPB with its two components, FP perspectives and FP actions are discussed. Finally, as a third element, the conceptual approach of the study is presented. It illustrates the overall analytical concept to accomplish the knowledge aim of this study.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Such a model could also be used for the analysis of how individuals ought to take decisions to solve their financial retirement issues. This research stream, which lies out of scope of this study, is known as “decision theory” and has, among others, been followed by Lindley 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  2. For simplification, a perfect capital market and zero real interest rates are assumed. See Shefrin/Thaler 1988, p. 611.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Thaler/ Benartzi 2004, p. 165.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Browning/ Crossley 2001, p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Rosenberg 2004 provides a comprehensive definition of saving as the mechanism that allows shifting consumption possibilities between periods: Saving is “the difference between disposable personal income and personal consumption expenditures; [it] includes the changes in cash and deposits, security holdings, indebtedness, reserves of life-insurance companies and mutual savings institutions, the net investment of unincorporated enterprises, and the acquisition of real property net of depreciation.” Rosenberg 2004, p. 311. This definition highlights that an increase in net real estate assets is considered as saving, an aspect that should be kept in mind in comparing saving rates between different countries. Furthermore, it is important to note that an increase in credits leads to a reduction of the saving rate, whereas paying off credits is considered as saving. The saving rate is defined as the ratio of personal saving to disposable personal income. Disposable personal income is specified as personal income less personal tax and non-tax-payments. See Downes/Goodman 1998, p. 534.

    Google Scholar 

  6. The homo economicus is used in traditional economic analyses. He is assumed to be a calculating, unemotional maximizer that is self-interested and rational. Without taking fairness, loyalty or the framing of decisions into consideration, he takes optimal decisions by rationally analyzing only the risk and reward profile. Building on the utility function of Von Neumann/Morgenstern 1947 that assigns different levels of utility to the various possible outcomes, the homo economicus always chooses the action with the highest expected utility. Optimization is thus his most powerful tool, deferral of consumption his sole motive for saving. See Mullainathan/Thaler 2000, p. 1, Thaler 1995, p. 9 or Kahneman et al. 1986, p. 285.

    Google Scholar 

  7. It has been shown that the standard assumptions about the homo economicus do not hold as individuals show deviations from rationality in terms of actions and judgments. For example, research has shown that individuals are not frame-invariant (e.g., the success of automatic enrollment plans for the saving rate shown by Madrian/Shea 2001) or that they are acting on the basis of mental accounts and are not invariant to the self-control problem. See Shefrin/Thaler 1988, p. 610. Also, they do not discount exponentially with a constant discount rate but apply hyperbolic discounting functions. See Laibson 1997. With regard to the specific assumptions of the standard life-cycle theory, it has been shown that post-retirement consumption is lower than pre-retirement consumption and thus households do not manage to smooth consumption across the retirement threshold. See Banks et al. 1998. Furthermore, the assumption that saving rates are “independent of income [...]is completely unsupported by the data, which shows that consumption very closely tracks income over individuals’ life-cycles.” Mullainathan/Thaler 2000, p. 8. Furthermore, it has been shown that deferral of consumption is not the only motive for saving but rather leaving an inheritance is also an important motive.

    Google Scholar 

  8. The idea of the permanent income hypothesis is that individuals will smooth their consumption based on their permanent (i.e., the anticipated, expected) income, which encompasses both the physical and human income streams. If individuals get an unexpected transitory income increase, this will not influence their consumption in the long run. See Friedman 1957.

    Google Scholar 

  9. The finding that the saving rate increases with the income level has also been demonstrated by Diamond/Hausman 1984, Davies 1981 and Mirer 1979.

    Google Scholar 

  10. See Mitchell/Utkus 2006, p. 83.

    Google Scholar 

  11. The distribution of expenses by age cited by Reimann 2006 shows that relative to the expenses in the age groups 34–45, the expense profile for individuals aged 65 and older shows an increase in healthcare costs and hobby-related expenses, while the expenses for transport, education and clothes are reduced. See Reimann 2006, p. 33.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See Eisenberg 2006, p. 35.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Certain individuals have historically even reached income levels that corresponded to their average pre-retirement income levels. An OECD survey has shown that in Germany in the mid 80s the disposable income of individuals aged 65 to 74 was over 80% of the income of the entire adult population (individuals aged 18 and over) and that this ratio increased to over 90% by the mid 90s. See OECD 2001, p. 27.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Evidence for continuing saving activity of retired individuals has been demonstrated by Mirer 1979 and Diamond/Hausman 1984. German evidence can be found at Börsch-Supan et al. 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Höllger/Sobull 2001 emphasize the increase in consumption in retirement as they state that today’s generation of retirees, the so-called “young old”, are part of the “consumption society”: When they still have a good health, they have a lot of time for traveling, cultural and social activities that are quite costly given that they have gotten used to a certain level of comfort and convenience. When the health level decreases, costs will increase due to medications and treatments as well as the use of special care and all kind of services. See Höllger/Sobull 2001, p. 39. The impact of a higher standard of living on an increasing consumption pattern is also confirmed by an empirical survey that states that “higher standards of living mean that what had been a satisfying retirement in the past may be viewed as insufficient in the future.” AXA 2006b, p. 21.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See Börsch-Supan et al. 2005, p. 18. For younger individuals this effect is less pronounced.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Mental accounts stand for cognitive activities that individuals engage in to serve the same function that regular accounting serves in an organization. Mental accounts lead to different propensities to consume certain mental pots of wealth. Shefrin/Thaler 1988 have found that “the elderly appear to spend money from their income account more readily than they draw down their assets, especially their housing wealth. Again this appears to represent voluntary behavior rather than capital market imperfections” as adequate products such as reverse mortgages are available. Shefrin/Thaler 1988, p. 633. See sub-section 4.2.3.3 on mental accounting.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Value at Risk can be understood “to mean the maximum loss or lowest gain which could occur at a given confidence level over a specified horizon, and it is based on both expected return and standard deviation.” Kritzman 2003, p. 173.

    Google Scholar 

  19. The model of life-cycle investing illustrated in Spremann 1995 explicitly includes an individual’s human capital (future income from work) besides the financial capital (wealth stock and its growth) as part of his total assets and also considers his liabilities to provide for his retirement. See Spremann 1995, p. 120.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Braun et al. 2002, p. 3f. The fact that an unprecedented amount of wealth is projected to change hands is especially important for the HNWI since the aging in that segment is particularly pronounced.

    Google Scholar 

  21. See for example Stiefermann 2005, p. 8 and Peape 2004, p. 24f.

    Google Scholar 

  22. CFP 2004, p. 1.

    Google Scholar 

  23. CFP 2004, p. 1.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Siegel et al. 1992, p. 230.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Richards 1986, p. 127.

    Google Scholar 

  26. See Tilmes 2001, p. 37.

    Google Scholar 

  27. See Wyder 2002, p. 35f.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Chieffe/ Rakes 1999, p. 263.

    Google Scholar 

  29. See for example Börsch-Supan/Wilke 2004, Börsch-Supan/Essig 2002, Börsch-Supan et al. 2003, Börsch-Supan et al. 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Siegel et al. 1992, p. 230.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Wyder 2002, for example, gives an overview of financial planning from a banking perspective. Richter 2001 focuses on the identification of general rules of guidance for performing financial planning activities. Tilmes 2001 focuses on the determinants of demand for financial services and the corresponding requirements for the offer of financial planning while Gebistorf 2004 analyzes the determinants of different financial planning pricing schemes.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Maginn/ Tuttle 1990, p. 1–3.

    Google Scholar 

  33. See UBS 2005, p. 30. The different steps in the definition of financial planning have been designed to reflect also the different elements described by Tilmes 2001, p. 31 or RICHARDS 1986, p. 127.

    Google Scholar 

  34. SEC 2005, Advisors Act Release No 1092, Supra Note 4.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Diliberto/ Anthony 2004, p. 30.

    Google Scholar 

  36. UBS distinguishes between “risk capability”, the objective ability to bear risk, and “risk tolerance”, an expression used to describe the subjective perspective on risk. See Peijan 2006, p. 28f. Bank Leu also recognizes these two elements and additionally defines a clear rule determining the overall “risk profile” by taking the lower of “risk ability” and “risk capability”. While “risk ability” is driven by wealth, income and expenditures, professional and social environment as well as the investment horizon, the “risk capability” depends on the reaction to risk, maximum acceptable losses, past experiences and the type of investor. See Leu 2006, p. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  37. “Risk aversion implies that if the expected return is held constant, people prefer the prospect with the smaller spread or variance. In particular, people always prefer a sure outcome over a risky prospect with the same expected value.” Tversky 1990, p. 73.

    Google Scholar 

  38. See Anderhub et al. 2001, p. 246f.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Shim/ Siegel 1991, p. 238.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Shefrin 2002, p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  41. With his paper on portfolio selection Markowitz 1952 examined the optimization of the choice of the individual constituents of a portfolio given a set of beliefs about the future performances of these securities. He did not investigate how these beliefs are formed.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Sharpe 1964 lays the basis for the CAPM.

    Google Scholar 

  43. See for example, Tversky 1990, Maginn/Tuttle 1990, Sharpe 1990 or Kaiser 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Cultural factors encompass the culture, sub-culture and social class. Culture determines the basic behavior of an individual, his attitudes and beliefs. Social factors include the reference group, family, social status and roles as well as the impact of opinion leaders. Social factors determine an individual’s behavior due to the interaction with specific groups and individuals as well as the role the individual plays in the different contexts. These cultural and social factors can be seen as external to the individual. Personal factors encompass observable elements that characterize an individual’s immediate situation, such as socio-demographic or socio-economic attributes (e.g., age and stage in the life-cycle, occupation and economic circumstances). They also include less observable aspects such as lifestyle, personal traits and self-perception. Psychological factors, finally, include activating elements such as motivation, with its sub-constructs, needs, emotions, mood and self-involvement, as well as cognitive elements such as learning and perception and beliefs and attitudes. Personal and psychological factors are internal elements. For a detailed description of the model or individual elements see Kotler/Bliemel 1995, p. 279ff, Kotler 1999, p. 161ff or Meffert 2000, p. 98ff and also Trommsdorff 1998, p. 47ff or Kroeber-Riel/Weinberg 1996, p. 53ff.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Credit Suisse for example distinguishes between individuals who need a balanced portfolio, those needing an income portfolio and finally those needing a capital gains portfolio. See Keating/Tschanz 2006, p. 5. UBS on the other hand speaks about conservative, moderate and aggressive investors. See UBS 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Kritzman 2003 describes a risk averse person as someone who would reject a fair game, a risk neutral person to be indifferent to such a game and a risk seeker to seek a fair game. Absolute risk aversion relates to the amount of wealth one is willing to expose to risk as one’s potential wealth increases. An absolute decreasing risk aversion indicates that this amount will increase with an increase in the overall potential wealth level; the constant absolute risk aversion means the amount will remain unchanged and an increasing absolute risk aversion means that the amount will decrease. Similarly, relative risk aversion refers to the percentage of wealth one is willing to expose to risk as wealth increases. He also states that most investors are indeed risk averse. See Kritzman 2003, p. 21ff.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Lindley 1990, p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2008 Physica-Verlag Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2008). Frame of reference and conceptual approach for the analysis of individual retirement-specific financial planning behavior. In: Individual Financial Planning for Retirement. Contributions to Economics. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-1998-4_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics